Why the GoI should consider revising the FRBM Act
The 2018 FRBMA amendment is characterized by a number of issues. This amendment envisaged a 40:20 split of the total government debt-to-GDP ratio between the central and state governments, while implicitly giving both a symmetrical fiscal deficit of 3% of GDP. This is an inconsistent combination as long as the underlying nominal GDP growth is the same for the GoI and the aggregate of states[1]. Further, this amendment gave up the target for achieving revenue account balance which was the primary feature of the 2003 FRBMA.
As the Indian economy progresses, it is important to recast its fiscal responsibility targets in the respective legislations of GoI and the state governments with the following features: (a) the target for keeping revenue account in balance or surplus should be brought back, (b) targets for fiscal deficit and debt relative to GDP should be symmetric between GoI and states at 30% and 3% respectively assuming an underlying nominal GDP growth of 11%. Further, the GoI may be provided with a flexibility up to +/- 2% points of GDP in the fiscal deficit target for macro stabilization (i.e. a range of 1% to 5% of GDP). During slowdown years it may be increased up to 5% of GDP. However, in subsequent years, when the economy has normalized it should be brought down suitably so as to keep an average fiscal deficit level of 3% of GDP. In case the crisis is much bigger, such as the Covid crisis, suitable variation in GoI’s and states’ fiscal deficit beyond the above range may be considered by an appropriate body such as a fiscal council which may be constituted either only to deal with that crisis or on a more permanent basis.
Linking revenue deficits to government dissavings and potential growth
Simply put, government dissavings, or revenue deficit is excess of government's revenue/operational expenditures over its revenues receipts from tax and non-tax sources. The recasting of FRF has to be placed in the broader perspective of India’s potential GDP growth. It is the availability of domestic savings supplemented by net inflow of foreign capital that provides the investible resources which combined with ICOR determines India’s potential growth.
As the first step, the fiscal deficit to GDP ratio is derived from the saving-investment profile of the economy. In particular, the supply of surplus savings emanates from the household (HH) sector in the form of household financial (HHF) savings which is then absorbed by three deficit sectors where investment demand is in excess of their own savings namely government sector (GG), non-government public sector (NGP), that is excluding administrative departments, and private corporate sector (PC). The net supply of investible resources is the sum of HHF savings and net inflow of foreign capital. Fiscal deficit constitutes the first claim on this supply of investible resources. Once fiscal deficit is specified, the balance becomes available for the remaining sectors.
Chart 2 shows that in a multi-country context, considering average per capita GDP during 2017-19, India’s saving rate should have been 20.1% of GDP if India were to be placed on the trend line. However, India’s actual nominal saving rate[2] was 29.5% implying that India enjoys a demographic dividend[3]-cum-cultural premium of 9.4% points.
This is what explains India’s ability to reach and sustain the position of a global growth leader at present. Assuming that this premium is maintained even as India reaches a higher per capita GDP level of US$14,005[4] (natural log of this is 9.5), consistent with a developed country status, India should have a nominal saving rate of 33.5% at the time of becoming Viksit.